To inflate or not to inflate? That is the question. ~ Jerome H. (Hamlet) Powell
The principal issue in the
eccentric world of macroeconomic policy-making focuses on inflation, as my currently-germane
alteration of Hamlet’s famous soliloquy states above. Is it rising and staying
for a while or is it merely a temporary drive-by event?
Even though a great deal depends on it, no one knows the answer. That’s despite economists’ reviewing decades of data and using their forecasting models day and night. That hasn’t stopped specialists from offering many differing opinions; following the adage, “often wrong, but never in doubt.” Perhaps macroeconomists should add trendspotting algorithms that have become popular in the fashion industry into their models.
For economists, inflation refers
to an increase in the overall level of a nation’s prices. More technically,
inflation occurs when aggregate prices of consumer goods and services rise due
to “excessive” demand or insufficient supply. As prices rise, the purchasing
value of money consequently falls.
Aggregate prices is a nebulous
macroeconomic concept referring to a measure of prices for all of our
nation’s final goods and services– from soap to syringes, and everything
in-between, like Buicks, donuts and urologist visits. Our most-often used
measure of inflation is the Consumer Price Index (CPI) that is calculated
monthly by the Labor Department’s Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS).
The CPI offers quite a few
different “flavors” of prices, like prices for urban consumers, for urban wage
earners and for the elderly. The BLS gathers data on consumer prices for each
of 211 different categories of consumer items (the “market basket” of goods and
services) in 38 different geographical areas throughout the US.
When the BLS released the May CPI
information on June 10, the media and others took serious note. During the last
12 months, the CPI increased 5.0%, the largest 12-month increase since August
2008. This annualized increase is over two times as large as the 2% inflation
rate that Mr. Powell, Chair of Federal Reserve Bank, hopes to see.
At the Fed’s summer meetings last
week, officials stated they would keep interest rates near zero, but explicitly
stated they would consider increasing rates, perhaps twice by the end of 2023
if inflation persists. This statement is a direct reaction to the May CPI
announcement. 2023 is a year sooner than the Fed has previously stated for considering
interest rate changes. The Fed thus has increased inflationary expectations.
Unsurprisingly, stock markets took that news poorly, dropping almost one
percent and bond yields increased.
The Fed steadfastly maintains
that current inflation is “transitory,” never defining what that term means. The
last two months have presented higher-than-expected annualized inflation, 4.2%
in April, 5.0% in May. If June’s CPI number is 4% or greater. it will be much
harder for the Fed to proclaim again it is transitory. We’ll know on July 13.
The Fed’s transitory belief rests
on two premises. First, aggregate production will continue to increase steadily
as recent parts shortages and supply-chain lags ameliorate, like chip-sets for autos
and trucks and lumber for construction. Second, consumers’ demand for goods and
services now reflects surging needs that were restricted during the extended
covid period; these will taper. Thus, after this temporary phase, markets will
get back to “more normal” behavior with more goods and services available and
less pent-up demand.
Most importantly, policy-makers need to adopt a more farsighted view of our economic activities, which is vital for producing well-founded economic programs. Monthly CPI data are interesting and instructive, just as weekly unemployment claims requests are. But these very short-term data are inherently quite variable. Their use should not be overemphasized, as they seemed to have become. Most economists are far better at drilling down for detailed information than we are at looking up. Adopting a broader, longer-term perspective will produce stronger, fairer policies.
The media have filled screens,
airwaves and newsprint with stories about how May’s unexpectedly large CPI reflected
price increases in specific slices of the economy. A Washington Post story
mentioned consumers are paying more for an array of products, including bacon and
used Buicks, as the economy rebounds strongly from the brief covid-led
recession.
Several items whose prices have
notably risen include used cars (Buicks and beyond), furniture, gasoline,
washing machines and dryers, bicycles, lumber and airfare. Beef and
non-Congressional pork prices have also risen.
But not to worry spending-fans.
In January, House Dems after a decade-long ban, resurrected personal earmarked
projects. These “pork” projects can be specifically-funded by a single
Congressperson that circumvent the standard merit-based and competitive
allocation process. How can you be upset at this change? There’s a $1.4
trillion per year limit for such projects. The Dems insist these pork-rind
earmarks will provide lawmakers new tools to better serve their communities,
and bring home the higher-priced bacon. Praise be? Not.
Back to Buicks. The mention of
old Buicks immediately recalled my grandfather’s, which looked much like the
one shown below. When we visited, he drove us in his sweet midnight-black,
side-portholed Buick on fine Sunday rides through Western Massachusetts countryside.
They don’t build them like that anymore.
A 1951 Buick Special cost $1,800,
which in today’s dollars is $18,637. The 2021 Buick Encore, the lowest-priced
model like the Special, costs $26,260. That’s fair amount of auto inflation, to
the tune of $7,623 more than the CPI-adjusted Special price. This 41% premium
accounts in part for the vast increases in Buicks’ automotive quality and
technical improvements gained by GM over the past 70 years.
Our inflation rates have steadily fallen during the last 50 years, as shown in this table. The average
Decade |
Average Yearly Inflation Rate |
1971-80 |
7.86% |
1981-90 |
4.74% |
1991-2000 |
2.81% |
2001-10 |
2.38% |
2011-20 |
1.73% |
Source: DOL/BLS |
After 1982, US annual inflation has
never been greater than 5.4%. Thus, any American younger than 40 years old
would think high inflation was more than 5%, at worst. Long gone are the nasty macroeconomic
mid-1970s and early 1980s, when inflation never got below 5.7%.
The most recent decade’s average
inflation rate was 1.73%, thankfully less than one-quarter the 1970s level. The
FFR currently remains a rock-bottom 0.06%, unemployment has been steadily dropping
since April 2020, now is 5.8%.
Although people remain concerned
about inflation, US price increases are far smaller than a several other
countries. Venezuela’s citizens have faced the world’s worst inflation for
years due to massive government malfeasance. Last years’ inflation in Venezuela
was a gigantic 9,568%, down from a stratospheric 1,698,488% in 2018. Venezuela’s
cumulative inflation from 2016 to early 2019 was estimated at 53,798,500%. This
unfathomable inflation is the reason Venezuela’s official minimum monthly
wage is currently worth only $3.20. Zimbabwe, always high in international
rankings, has the second-topmost inflation at 767%. Such giant hyperinflation rates
are usually caused by the government’s oversized increase in the money supply
that cannot be warranted by (absent) economic growth.
Meanwhile back in Washington, Dems
in Congress continue wrestling with how to fund the administration’s expansive infrastructure
programs. Fearing that their more moderate colleagues’ nascent, bipartisan $1
trillion (T) effort will ignore many of their priorities, progressive Dems’
latest idea is to combine all their sprawling hopes into one single, giant
effort, perhaps as large as $6T – a wish-list including most Prog favorites. The
combined $7T possible infrastructure spending would represent 33% of our
current GDP. No matter how worthy such outlays might be, they would likely
unleash intimidating inflationary pressures.
Each of these bills face formidable
odds of passing in no small part because they will require every Senate Dem to
vote for them. Approving a single, $6T bill for widely-demarcated
infrastructure will push way beyond Senate prospects. One other hindrance is Congress’
feeble work schedule. House members plan to toil in Washington only 9 days
between now and Labor Day; Senators just 16 days. The House will not be in
session at any time in August. Legislative life on Capitol Hill is indeed very
different from other workplaces. Does such a schedule justify why we taxpayers
provide these “legislators” with a perhaps-inflated $174,000 salary?
Bruce, well said about the short term effects of why there is inflation on a few items. My question is the long term effects of the former Jackass' tax cuts on the economy as whole.
ReplyDelete